Implications Increase of Protectionism Between
USA and China for International Business
ZDZISŁAW W. PUŚLECKI
Adam Mickiewicz University, Poznań
ul. Uniwersytetu Poznańskiego 5
61-614 Poznań
POLAND
Abstract - The main aim of this paper is presentation the implications increase of protectionism between the
United States and China on international business. The main objective of the research task is to give a
comprehensive analysis of current trends in foreign trade theory and policy and in particularly the models of
foreign trade policy, trade interests indicated by export orientation and import sensitivity, protectionist pressures
in different political system, the level of protectionist pressures, new tendencies in international business, reasons
for the USA to implement tariff sanctions. China will be significantly hurt by tariff trade war in all indicators,
including welfare, gross domestic product (GDP), manufacturing employment and trade. However, it is pointed
out that although there will be definite impacts on China, the costs should be maintainable and will not severely
damage the Chinese economy. In regard to the United States, the simulation produced results that described, the
US will gain on welfare, GDP and non-manufacturing production, but hurt employment and trade.
Key-Words:- USA, China, protectionism, international business, supply chains, trade war.
Received: December 11, 2022. Revised: August 28, 2023. Accepted: September 22, 2023. Published: November 7, 2023.
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
175
Volume 1, 2023
1 Introduction
Both structural and micro-political economy
analyses of foreign trade policy have missed the
impact of changing ideas about protectionism and
relatively unchanging institutions designed to handle
domestic producer complaints. The political
consensus on the supply of the trade policy and
protectionism has changed over the time. During
economic depression protectionism played
important roles in the politics of political parties and
increased the importance of bilateral agreements and
regional agreements. This point of view is very
important for the theory and practice of the
contemporary international business also between
USA and China.
The necessity for companies to organize their
supply chains across different countries has led to a
demand for the regional agreements that cover more
than preferential tariffs. The harmonization of
standards and rules on investment, intellectual
property and services has become a standard part of
new trade agreements. The differences among
companies which are involved in trade are also
important for the future development. The concept
that arises from the trade is that even if many
companies are indirectly involved into the trade-
related activities, only relatively few of them are
exporting or importing. Accordingly, these
companies tend to be larger and more productive
than others. Such companies also have a role in
technology advancement and the diffusion of know-
how through supply chains. It should be emphasised
also that free trade in itself is not responsible for
economic growth, but more significant are the
determining macroeconomic stability and increasing
investment.
The international trade in the XXI century has
been strongly affected by the force of the domestic
interests like in the USA under President Donald
Trump’s administration with the principle America
First. The changes are visible in the growing
importance of international trade to national
economies and domestic groups within those
economies, in the closer linkages between trade and
other international issues. Realistic point of view is
the essential trends in the global trade regime during
this time. The growing interdependence has led to
increased competitiveness and greater inclinations
to resort to strategic trade policy.
2 Research and Methodology
The primary research objective of this paper is to
conduct a comprehensive analysis of the potential
implications of the United States and China
increasing their trade barriers. China will be
significantly hurt by a tariff trade war in all
indicators, including welfare, GDP, manufacturing
employment, and trade. However, it has been
pointed out that, although China will be significantly
affected, the costs should be sustainable and not
severely damage the Chinese economy. As for the
United States, the simulation results indicate that
there will be welfare, GDP and non-manufacturing
production gains, but employment and trade losses.
Both quantitative and qualitative research
methods were used for analytical purposes. The
main research method applied in this analysis was a
method of scientific study that breaks down a whole
(of individual items, their sets, and various
phenomena) by means of logical abstraction. The
analogy (comparative) method, which consists in
finding similarities and differences between the
items under study, the documentation method, and
various statistical methods were also applied, as
were other descriptive statistics and forecasting
methods. Finally, deductive and inductive
forecasting were employed.
3 Results and Discussion
The importance and innovativeness of this research
lies in the fact that it reveals the potential
implications of the increasing protectionism
between the United States and China. First, it
emphasizes the importance of “factor specificity” (a
new theoretical term) in the demand for trade policy.
Some factors have retained their existing uses.
Factor returns are therefore not equalized throughout
a region’s economy, but are industry specific. Trade
policy coalitions should be formed along the lines of
exporting versus import-competing industries.
Understanding the choice between liberal and
protectionist trade policies is therefore crucial at the
theoretical level.
What is at issue is how to recognize the type of
power or rule at play. First, the level of resources
that can be achieved by a given government has to
be investigated. How much more income an
authoritarian government can generate through
protectionism depends on how corrupt it is
compared to its democratic trading partner(s). It will
also appropriate some part of that income. Secondly,
any government, whatever its political system or
power structure, is susceptible to pressure from
special interest groups, including regulated labor.
No government, no matter how authoritarian, can
subordinate these groups unless it transfers some of
the income generated by its protectionist policies to
them.
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
176
Volume 1, 2023
The close relationship between democracy and
economic growth is worth noting. Examples of open
societies stimulating economic growth are not hard
to find. This is especially true in the case of highly
developed and urbanized countries. Pressure groups
potentially have more influence over the
government in a developed democracy. Research
shows that trade unions help accelerate economic
reforms. The benefits of liberalizing international
trade are greater when the protected sectors of the
economy are unionized. The growth of import
abilities leads to a decrease in wage pressures. If the
trade unions accept this, then labor can be more
efficiently allocated. This is true in the case of both
active and passive trade unions, although active
trade unions obviously achieve better results.
Increasing interdependence has led to greater
competitiveness and more inducements to resort to
strategic trade policy. Trade policy assumes further
significance in the economic battle of valiant liberal
reformers in their fight against self-dealing rent
seekers profiting from inconsistencies in the
transition economy. Many of the client policies that
shelter rent seekers are impossible to maintain in the
face of international competition. On the other hand,
high tariff walls, export licensing, and artificial
exchange rates provide numerous sources of rents
for businesspeople out to promote their own
loyalties.
The reduction or elimination of trade
restrictions significantly stimulates world trade and
conversely, foreign trade is an important factor
driving the economic growth of individual countries.
However, it should be stressed that free trade is not
the sole contributing factor to economic growth;
macroeconomic stability and investment are more
significant.
It has to be stressed that if unemployment is
increasing and/or inequality widening while global
supply chains are expanding and multiplying, and if
most voters attribute the former to the latter, then
governments may well refrain from pursuing further
international trade liberalization and might even find
protectionism alluring. Another possibility would be
for governments to use more intensively public
policies for protectionist purposes. As for trade
negotiations, focusing exclusively on the increased
efficiency resulting from opening up trade is no
longer possible. Distribution and labor-market
effects also need to be considered and various
measures proposed in order to win the electorate
over to open trade by bilateral agreement, especially
at times when global supply chains are expanding
and multiplying.
As global supply chains have expanded and
multiplied, the formulation of new theoretical
models of the firm have made it possible to explore
the effects that differences in firms have had on the
political economy of trade. It has to be stressed that
opening up trade has had two opposing effects on
domestic firms in the same industry. First, the cost
of exporting decreases, which obviously allows
more firms to export and increases the sales of
established exporters. Secondly, competition
increases, which harms domestic firms. Which of
these opposing tendencies prevails for an individual
firm depends on such characteristics as size. As a
result, lobbying competition arises not only between
sectors but also within sectors with the inevitable
result that there are winners and losers. This might
especially be the case when costs are fixed, because
barriers to entry are raised, thereby shielding
existing producers and exporters from competition.
Current trends in international business and
global politics provide evidence that emerging
markets have finally made their presence felt on the
world economy, bringing new patterns of uneven
development, inequality and injustice in their wake.
Their newly confident elites, now active on global
circuits of trade, investment and finance, and in
global governance, appear to have shed their
previous roles. It is clear that emerging economies
have suffered less severely and recovered more
quickly. Moreover, it now seems that the political
impact is not so much immediate crisis measures,
but significant, long-term and unexpected policy
shifts.
3. 1 Political Economy Model of Foreign Trade
Policy
Traditionally, political economy models of trade
policy have tended to focus on demands for
protection, with factor endowments driving political
reactions to exposure to international trade. These
models simply assumed that adversely affected
economic agents would organize and lobby their
elected political representatives for protection. The
supply side for trade policy was either ignored or
underspecified in most models [50].
Some of the reviews of the new model of
foreign trade policy theory are interesting insofar as
they concern the demand for trade policy in terms of
the theoretical importance of factor specificity [2]
[26]. Factor specificity refers to the ease with which
factors (land, labor, and capital) can move from one
sector to another in an economy. The two dominant
approaches to explaining the demand side of trade
policy used radically different assumptions about the
specificity of factors. The Heckscher-Ohlin model,
used by Rogowski (1989) in his seminal
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
177
Volume 1, 2023
contribution Commerce and Coalitions, assumes
very low-factor specificity [46]. Low factor
specificity means that factor returns are equalized
throughout a region’s economy. Producers should
export goods that intensively use their abundant
factors and import goods that intensively use their
scarce factors, with the result that owners of
abundant factors will favor free trade and owners of
scarce factors will favor protectionism. Trade policy
coalitions will therefore be organized along factor or
class lines. The Ricardo-Viner model, per contra,
assumes that some factors are stuck in their present
uses and that factor returns are therefore not
equalized throughout a region’s economy, but are
industry specific. Trade policy coalitions should
form along the lines of exporting versus import-
competing industries.
Neither of these models explains how
preferences over trade policies are actually
translated into political action [2]. In a discussion of
the endogenous tariff literature, Nelson (1988) notes
that the mobility costs of the specific-factors model
may be a result of productivity differentials, labor
union activity, or individual preferences for
membership in a given geographical area, industry,
or firm (i.e. some form of solidarity) [26]. In all of
these cases, a link to tariff policy preferences can be
derived, “but without additional information on why
the specific-factor model is chosen, it does not tell
us much about political organization”.
Alt et al. (1996) suggest that we can begin to
understand this process by assuming that rational
individuals make cost/benefit calculations [2]. The
Heckscher-Ohlin and Ricardo-Viner models
enumerate the benefits that individuals hope to
receive, but the costs of collective action also
intervene as they organize to achieve those benefits
in the political system. Olson (1985) argued that
small special-interest groups are easier to organize
and more effective in securing economic rents than
large groups with diffuse interests [27]. Small
groups are better able to control free riders than large
groups, and groups with specific or homogenous
interests can more easily coordinate and target their
activities than groups with diffuse or heterogenous
interests [35]. This approach is thought to explain
the success of agricultural producer groups in
developed countries in organizing for protection
[35] as well as the inability of agricultural producer
group to organize in developing countries [3] [7]
[27][28][49].
However, Nelson (1988) points out that
organized interests should not be assumed to be
equally responsive to all issues [26].
Institutionalized interaction among actors may help
to explain systematic patterns of action, especially
as institutions created for specific historical
purposes may outlive those purposes. Alt et al.
(1996) suggest that if a particular group has paid the
fixed costs of establishing collective action and
developed well-worn channels of access to public
officials, it may defend its trade policy preferences
even when the stakes are low because the marginal
costs of action are low [2]. It may be the case that “a
much more affected but inchoate group does nothing
because the start-up costs of organization are too
daunting [35]. Past strength of an organization
should therefore be an important intervening
variable predicting group action on trade policy.
Further, as Nelson (1988) argues, once these
institutions exist, supply-side interventions may also
affect their usefulness as some are deemed
legitimate or illegitimate aggregators of interest
[26]. The ways in which economic institutions and
political institutions interact must therefore be
examined. Most economic models simply assume
that a model of the economy is a model of the
demand side for trade policy, but Nelson (1988)
suggests that we have to elaborate the mechanism by
which demand is articulated to the suppliers of trade
policy [26]. For a good overview of this argument,
especially as it pertains to agriculture [50].
If the political system rewards small sectoral
groups, then individuals will decline to incur the
costs of organizing large intersectoral coalitions. If
the political system rewards large mass movements
(i.e. majoritarianism), then individuals will have to
incur the costs of organizing large intersectoral
coalitions in order to achieve any benefits. The costs
of collective action and the nature of political
institutions interact with factor specificity. This
suggests that Rogowski’s (1989) Heckscher-Ohlin
framework requires low factor specificity, low
collective action costs, and domestic political
institutions that favor mass movements [46]. The
Ricardo-Viner framework used by the endogenous
tariff literature requires specific factors, high
collective action costs, and non-majoritarian
institutions. The nature and extent of these three
variables affects the type of coalitions that form.
In the state as rational dictator model, the state
may be seen as either pursuing “good government”
goals along a social welfare function or intervening
in the economy for its own interests. This model
views politicians as offering preferential trade policy
to economic actors in exchange for political support
[24] [13]. On the other hand, pluralist theory
typically views the state as a neutral aggregator of
demands from groups in society. The supply side of
trade policy is then determined by the balance of
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
178
Volume 1, 2023
power on any given issue. This is still in the early
stages of theoretical development, but is vitally
important. Various characteristics of the political
system are posited to affect the supply of trade
protectionism, such as incentives for politicians to
cultivate personal votes, the size of electoral
districts, party fragmentation, federal versus unitary
structures, presidential versus parliamentary
systems, etc. [45] [47] [48].
Understanding the trade policies adopted by
different countries is crucial at the theoretical level.
A 1984 survey of economists found that one of the
few things they agreed on was that, under most
conditions, tariffs, and quotas reduce general
welfare [10]. The persistence of protectionism in the
face of international and academic resistance has led
economists to seek explanations. These explanations
range from simple ignorance on the part of
politicians to the (questionable) rationality of having
to protect “infant industries” and the need for
developing states to impose “optimal tariff levels”.
Scholars have increasingly turned to politics in order
to explain apparently irrational policy decisions out
of sheer frustration [10]; [25]; [26].
3. 2 Protectionist Pressures in Different Political
Systems
It is important to note that trade unions can play very
different roles in different political systems. As a
rule, their role is smaller in authoritarian systems
than it is in democratic systems. The prospects for
economic growth are obviously more promising
when the trade unions are unable to exert undue
protectionist pressure. This line of reasoning
justifies the conclusion that authoritarian systems
are more conducive to labor market efficiency, and
the examples of Chile, South Korea, Singapore and
Turkey during the 1970s and early 1980s could be
said to bear this out. Many authoritarian regimes
persecuted trade unions and restricted basic labor
rights during those two decades. However, South
Korea, Singapore and Turkey experienced
spectacular growth in their processing industries and
in the demand for labor throughout that oppressive
period. Greater profitability and the increasing
demand for labor in the processing industry made
the workforce more prosperous. Although similar
results were not noted immediately during the
authoritarian development phase in Chile, a number
of observers are of the opinion that the reforms
introduced at that time contributed to the
reorganization of the Chilean economy in the 1990s.
The application of democratic norms, by contrast,
can lead to lower labor productivity. During the
period in question, several democratic countries
were obliged to employ trade union members at
considerable extra cost.
An alternative viewpoint has it that labor
legislation can be applied more effectively in an
authoritarian system than it can in a democratic one.
Authoritarian regimes often exploit the specific
interests of various groups. Few democratic
countries have a broad enough consensus to win the
support of pressure groups (the urbanized labor
market elite included) by means of labor market
policy. The major difference between authoritarian
and democratic regimes lies in the level of influence
that can be exerted on the government and by whom.
In a well-functioning democracy, various, often
conflicting, viewpoints have to be accommodated
and special interest groups constrained. In a
dictatorship, by contrast, the government is only
concerned to see that these groups do not become too
powerful [35].
There are, however, several democracies
among both the industrialized and developing
countries that have an effective labor market.
Moreover, an effective labor market is often a
priority in countries moving away from
authoritarianism towards democracy.
It is worth considering which of the two
viewpoints presented above should be adopted. The
Grossman and Helpman model [13] may be of
assistance here. This model describes economic
development in terms of the urbanized, regulated
processing sector, and the rural, unregulated
agricultural sector. Labor protection legislation,
especially minimum wage laws, is obviously
designed to benefit the regulated sector.
Not surprisingly, the regulated labor force, and
employers, demand that the government formulate
economic policies favorable to them. Workers
demand high minimum wages and their employers
demand high profits. Both groups demand that
restrictions be placed on the openness of the
economy. In a closed economy, higher minimum
wages and profits are usually correlated with higher
prices for domestic consumers, as imported
substitutes are not readily available. Protection can
therefore generate income, which can then be
divided among workers and their employers in the
regulated sector, although the government
sometimes appropriates part of it [5].
Governments have to consider several
factors when implementing economic policy.
Firstly, they have to determine their share of the
anticipated benefits. This explains the importance of
investment and economic growth, and of assessing
the likelihood of maintaining power. Secondly, the
level of support that can be expected from each of
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
179
Volume 1, 2023
the pressure groups capable of influencing the
situation needs to be specified. The position and
importance of each group for the development of
political processes has to be carefully weighed [60].
For example, if the regulated labor market is divided
and politically weak, then only employers might
have any real say in the political process. The
opposite can also occur; a well organized labor force
can play a major role in mobilizing voters.
How can we recognize the type of power?
Firstly, the benefits the government has set out to
deliver need to be identified. Whether an
authoritarian government can generate more income
than a democratic one through protectionism largely
depends on how corrupt it is. The government can
also be counted on to appropriate part of that
income. Secondly, the government may be
influenced by various pressure groups. When an
authoritarian government attempts to subordinate
special-interest pressure groups, including the
regulated labor sector, it inevitably transfers some of
the income generated through protection to them.
3. 3 Level of Protectionist Pressures
The above arguments show that policy is shaped by
political factors (including the type of government
and its obligations towards employers and
employees), and by economic factors (wages, prices,
the structure of production and consumption). In
light of the present discussion, we can present two
equations: one pertaining to the level of protection,
and the other to the national economy and
deformation of wages.
(1) = f (e, l, k, R)
(2) = f1 (, e, l, k, R).
The level of protection () is a function of
the economic parameters (e), the relative political
importance of the urbanized labor force and its
employers (l and k, respectively), and on the type of
government (R). Wage distortions are a function of
and of e, l, k and R. In the case of a small economy,
economic parameters that can influence and
include the flexibility of consumer and producer
prices and demand, wages, the demand for labor, and
the price of goods on the international market.
By definition, the growth of is dependent on l
and k. When interest groups become stronger, there
is greater pressure to raise income through
protectionism. The influence of R (the degree of
authoritarianism) on (the level of protectionism)
depends on whether depends on the nature and
extent of democratization. It is also thought that
wage distortion increases with and l, and decreases
with k. So long as the extra income is obtained from
trade protection, it can be distributed among the
urbanized labor force. However, one major problem
facing the urbanized labor force, as a special interest
group gaining in strength, is that any potential gains
in the division of income may be offset by the
political clout of its employers with the result that it
will actually receive a smaller share in regulated
sectors of the economy [9].
It is obviously easier for wealthy societies to
choose democracy than it is for poor ones.
Moreover, as wealthy societies also tend to be more
open, the direction of causation may run from a
society’s level of openness to its political system,
and not vice versa, as suggested earlier. Research
also shows that educational level plays an important
role in this respect. Countries with higher
educational levels tend to be more open.
The above considerations warrant the
conclusion that authoritarian systems tend to apply
protectionism more broadly than democratic
systems, and that trade restrictions are correlated
with significant wage distortions. This can be
justified on the basis of the observable situation in a
number of countries.
Freedom of association is a sign of good
management and a precondition for development.
Authoritarian governments, however, do not respect
freedom of association. To do so would run counter
to their policies of restricting trade and distorting the
labor market. That is not to say, however, that
improper or ineffective labor market policies are the
preserve of authoritarian regimes or that
authoritarianism automatically generates this kind of
policy. There are any number of examples of
authoritarian countries which do not pursue such
policies. The works of such authors as Fields or
Freeman show that it is not necessary to keep
workers down to achieve the desired level of
economic growth.
Finally, it should be noted that there is a close
relationship between democracy and economic
growth, Indeed, there are well-documented cases of
open societies stimulating economic growth. This is
especially true in the case of highly developed and
urbanized countries. Pressure groups have greater
scope for action in countries with a developed
democracy. Research shows that trade unions can
accelerate economic reform. The benefits of
liberalizing international trade are greater when the
protected sectors of the economy are unionized.
Increased import opportunities reduce wage
pressures. If the trade unions accept this, then labor
can be more efficiency allocated. This is true both in
the case of active and passive trade unions, although
the former obviously achieve better results.
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
180
Volume 1, 2023
Trade unions active on urbanized labor
markets significantly influenced government
decision-making during the WTO multilateral trade
negotiations. This was especially evident during the
negotiations on lowering customs duties and non-
tariff protection measures in the steel, shipbuilding,
textile and clothing industries, and in coal mining.
The trade unions were particularly strong in
“sensitive” industries, which were under special
trade protection.
3. 4 New Tendencies in International Business
Countries and producers increasingly specialize in
certain stages of production depending on
comparative advantage [20][25]. This is an
important development for foreign trade policy. It
should also be emphasized that transport and energy
costs partly explain why supply chains are still
mostly regional. Krugman (1991) incorporates
increasing returns, together with capital and labor
migration and transport costs, into a single
model. Krugman’s (1991) model has become a
workhorse of economic geography and international
trade. It is too complex to explain here, but the
reasons for that complexity are clear when
everything becomes "endogenous", small variations
in a single factor can have huge knock-on
effects. For example, in order to minimize transport
costs, firms want to be near actual and potential
customers, consumers want to be close to goods and
services providers, and workers want to be close to
where they can find work. There are therefore
multiple equilibria, and there can be a tipping point
where the location decisions of a single firm,
customer and/or worker can snowball. A related
trend is a new form of regionalism that is sometimes
referred as integration process development [4].
It needs to be emphasized that openness to trade
with China is associated with higher incomes and
growth and that there need to be new approaches to
trade in light of the forces that are currently re-
shaping international business. A major factor in this
has been the remarkable transformation of China, as
market reforms have opened up its economy to
foreign trade and investment, and unleashed
unprecedented economic growth. This is ongoing
and has only witnessed minor slowdowns. Under the
conditions in which the global economy and global
trade are developing, the People’s Republic of China
appears to be a production superpower that can
change world trade and influence the rise of global
supply chains. The country has a comparative
advantage in many areas and is moving to specialize
in electronics and increasingly in services.
The major trend in international trade is the
rise of several emerging economies and the
associated increase in their shares in world trade
[25]. This applies especially to China, but India and
Brazil have also altered the balance of power in the
multilateral trading system [25]. Between 1980 and
2011, for example, China’s share in world
merchandise exports and imports increased tenfold,
making the country the largest exporter of the world
[25] [22].
The industrialization and spectacular growth of
emerging economies, together with the rapid
expansion of trade in services and of FDI, are
inextricably linked to the next intensive phase of
production growth. The focus here will be on how
the rise of global supply chains can impact the
political economy of trade and on how to induce
countries to work together on bilateral trade policies
[16]. That participation in global supply chains tends
to strengthen anti-protectionist forces has both
theoretical and empirical support [16]. The main
impact has been unilateral tariff reductions (mostly
among developing countries), and the proliferation
of preferential trade agreements (PTAs) and bilateral
investment treaties [20][16]. A considerable amount
of trade opening has thus taken place outside the
WTO.
The internationalization of supply chains has
proven vital for the rapid economic development and
industrialization of developing countries. Before the
emergence of supply chains and the information
and communications technology (ICT) revolution
that underpinned them industrialization involved
building a strong industrial base, often behind a wall
of tariffs and other protective measures (NTMs)[17].
The unbundling of global production has enabled
countries to industrialize by joining international
supply chains [16]. This process has also changed
the political economy of trade policy, and created a
strong incentive to undertake unilateral tariff
reductions in many developing countries.
3. 5 The Structure of Political System
The US claims that Chinese state-owned enterprises
are typical by-products of a communist planned
economy, and that crony capitalist princelings
derive the greatest benefits from most of their
initiatives, including the Belt and Road Initiative
[29][40][44][39] and Made in China 2025. The US,
Japan, Canada, Mexico, and the EU do not recognize
China as a market economy, alleging market
distortions. Economist Irwin Stelzer states that
China's centrally directed economy, designed to
preserve communist party control of the nation’s
politics and its economy, is relevant to US trade
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
181
Volume 1, 2023
policy. Aaron Friedberg, a political scientist and
former White House national security officer, has
also said the communist Chinese regime has
considerably expanded its use of state-directed,
market-distorting, mercantilist policies since 2008
[33]. The 2018 Congressional hearing “U.S. Tools
to Address Chinese Market Distortions” discussed
how “the Party leads everything” doctrine makes it
difficult to apply trading rules to the Chinese
economy and results in many US businesses bowing
to pressure, even though their decisions risk
jeopardizing the future of their companies and the
US economy as a whole. The Chinese Communist
Party is fundamentally opposed to free-market
capitalism and fair competition. The US cites this as
the root cause of US–China economic tensions [29].
China is a totalitarian mercantilist regime in a
state of an economic war with the West. Trade war
by China against the United States has been going
on for years” (Fig. 1). China declared trade war on
the US 18 years ago in control and command
economies like China, a telephone call in the middle
of the night from a monopoly commissar is all that
it takes to get a business to do something (Fig. 1).
China is totalitarian regime and states China's unfair
trade
Fig. 1: The rapidly increasing US trade imbalance
with China.
policies are kind of economic aggression and a direct
result of its autocracy. The economic security is the
national security and discusses trade in a broader
geopolitical arena.
China counterclaims that the US government
has long practiced unilateralism, protectionism and
economic hegemony, made false accusations against
many countries and regions, particularly China,
intimidated other countries through economic
sanctions such as tariffs, and attempted to impose its
own interests on China through duress.
China has stolen US intellectual property and
bullied its way into acquiring critical US advances
in technology. Tariffs are an important tool to put an
end to trade practices that are destroying American
jobs and driving down American wages.
Many countries and companies have accused
Chines spies and hackers of stealing technological
and scientific secrets by installing malware and
infiltrating industries, institutions, and universities.
China has also been accused of stealing foreign
designs, flouting product copyrights and
implementing a two-tier patent system that
discriminates against foreign companies with
unreasonably longer times. The Chinese intelligence
service was accused of assisting Chinese companies
by stealing company secrets.
Chinese hackers have consistently stolen
trade secrets from US defense contractors. Chinese
cybertheft of intellectual property is the greatest
transfer of wealth in history. Chinese spies have
gone after private defense contractors and
subcontractors, national laboratories, public
research universities, think tanks, and even the US
government. Chinese agents have gone after crucial
US defense assets, such as the F-35 Lightning,
the Aegis Combat System, and the Patriot Missile
System. They have illegally appropriated unmanned
underwater vehicles and thermal imaging cameras,
and have stolen documents related to the B52
Bomber, the Delta IV Rocket, the F15 Fighter, and
even the Space Shuttle. The US opened a formal
investigation into attacks on the intellectual property
of the US and its allies, which was costing the US
alone an estimated $225–600 billion a year.
3. 6 Reasons for the USA to Impose Tariff
Sanctions
China and the United States are engaged in a trade
war, with each disputing the tariffs the other
imposes on its goods. These economic disputes
began before China joined the World Trade
Organization (WTO). In April 2018, the United
States filed a request for consultation to the WTO in
regard to concerns that China was
violating intellectual property rights.
By adding various tariffs, the US
administration is partly relying on Section 301 of the
Trade Act of 1974 to prevent what it calls unfair
trade practices and theft of intellectual
property. This gives the president the authority to
unilaterally impose fines or other penalties on a
trading partner if it is deemed to be unfairly harming
US business interests, especially if it is deemed to
have violated international trade agreements. In
August 2017, the US opened a formal investigation
into attacks on the intellectual property of the US
and its allies.
The result is that the US believes Chinese
laws undermine intellectual property rights by
forcing foreign companies to engage in joint
ventures with Chinese companies, which then gives
these companies access to foreign technologies and
permission to appropriate, copy and use them. The
US has also raised concerns that China refuses to
recognize legitimate patents and copyrights,
discriminates against foreign imported
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
182
Volume 1, 2023
technology, and has instituted numerous non-tariff
barriers to effectively insulate sectors of the Chinese
economy from international competition. Thus, the
trade war is seen as largely focused on intellectual
property, especially in the area of science and
technology.
China’s technological progress is coming
from businesspeople who are benefitting from the
vast sums their government invests in basic science.
The Chinese education system privileges excellence
and focuses on science and technology. That’s
where their leadership in some technologies is
coming from, not from taking a stake in some US
company. China declared that its attitude toward the
protection of intellectual property rights is clear and
firm, and it has continuously strengthened protection
at the legislative, law enforcement, and judicial
levels, with remarkable results.
The US claims that China requires technology
transfer through a Foreign Direct
Investment (FDI) regime and often requires joint
ventures: in many cases, technology transfers are
effectively required by China's FDI regime, which
closes off important sectors of the economy to
foreign firms. In order to gain access to these sectors,
China forces foreign companies to enter into joint
ventures with Chinese entities with which they have
no connection.
A number of experts have focused on what they
claim is China's “theft” of intellectual property,
saying that China forces any US company wanting
to do business there to transfer confidential
technology and trade secrets before it will grant
access to its market. Although that kind of transfer
is in breach of WTO rules, the negotiations are
usually conducted in secret to avoid penalties. The
Commission on the Theft of American Intellectual
Property states claims that agreeing to manufacture
in China is tantamount to agreeing to transfer
technology or have it stolen. The Commission
recommended a response based on “strength and
leverage”.
In 2018, the American Chamber of
Commerce in China learned that over half its
members cited “leakage of intellectual property” as
an important concern when doing business there.
Similarly, the EU Chamber of Commerce has also
complained that European companies wanting
access to the Chinese market often have to agree to
transfer vital technology. China claims that
technical, economic, and trade cooperation between
Chinese and foreign enterprises is completely based
on contracts voluntarily entered into, that both
companies obtain practical benefits, and that over
the years, US companies in China have not only
benefitted enormously through technology transfer
and licensing, but are the biggest beneficiaries of
technical cooperation.
In June 2016, as presidential candidate,
Donald Trump vowed to cancel international trade
deals and go on an offensive against Chinese
economic practices, describing his promise as a
reaction against "a leadership class that worships
globalism". Less than a year after he took office, the
United States, European Union and Japan, agreed to
work within the World Trade Organization (WTO)
and other multilateral groups to eliminate unfair
subsidies by countries, which create noncompetitive
conditions through state-owned enterprises,
“forced” technology transfers and local content
requirements.
In April 2018, President Donald Trump
denied that the dispute was actually a trade war,
saying that war was lost many years ago by the
foolish, or incompetent, people who represented the
US. He added also that in the 2018 year USA have
a trade deficit of $500 billion a year, with
intellectual property (IP) theft of another $300
billion (Fig. 2) and that US cannot let this continue.
Fig. 2: US Trade Representative.
In January 2018, President Donald Trump
underlined he wanted the United States to have a
good relationship with China, but insisted that it treat
the United States fairly. In his State of the Union
Address a few weeks later, mentioned that America
has also finally turned the page on decades of unfair
trade deals that sacrificed prosperity and shipped
away companies, jobs, and Nation’s wealth. The era
of economic surrender is over. From this time
America expect trading relationships to be fair and
to be reciprocal. United States will work to fix bad
trade deals and negotiate new ones and US
government will protect American workers and
American intellectual property, through strong
enforcement of US trade rules.
A number of government and industry experts
have offered their own rationales as to why tariffs
are, or are not, appropriate. John Ferriola, the CEO
and President of Nucor, America's largest steel
producer and metal recycler, argued that tariffs were
not unfair, but were “simply leveling the playing
field”. Ferriola went on to explain that most
countries, including EU member states, levy VAT
rates of at least 25% on US imports. If the US
imposed a 25% tariff, it would therefore be doing no
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
183
Volume 1, 2023
more than treating these countries exactly as they
treat the US.
It is claimed that China has instituted an array
of non-tariff barriers and that this has shielded
critical sectors of the Chinese economy from
international competition. China has controlled
imports by having different standards for private,
foreign companies than for Chinese State Owned
companies. Lee G. Branstetter, a professor of
economics and public policy at Carnegie Mellon
University, has listed some of the ways that China
has misappropriated foreign technology. In a report
dated March 22, 2018, the US cited numerous
instances of forced technology transfer and the
failure of companies and the government to protect
US intellectual property from infringement or theft.
Soon after the report came out, the US announced
plans to impose tariffs on up to $60 billion worth of
Chinese exports to the United States and to tighten
the rules governing Chinese investment in the
United States.
Despite doubts being raised over US strength
and leverage, security implications, and China's
appalling human rights record, the Clinton
administration approved WTO membership for
China in 2000. However, the US claims that China
has failed to fulfill its promise to implement reforms
and meet the requirements of WTO membership,
and that flaws in the rules of the current trading
system allow China to limit imports with high tariffs
and discriminatory regulations, to subsidize exports
with an inexpensive currency and readily available
credit on easy terms (courtesy of state controlled
banks), bully foreign investors, and pirate western
intellectual property. The US claims that the WTO
has declined to take action against China’s
“cheating”.
China had agreed to purchase “a very substantial”
amount of soy beans and other agricultural, energy,
industrial, and other products from the US. China
had agreed to reduce the 40% tariff on cars imported
from the US, although Beijing had yet to confirm
this as at December 4, 2018. The Chinese
government was considering a reduction in the auto
tariff but provided no specifics. China and the US
had agreed to immediately begin negotiations on
structural changes with respect to forced technology
transfer, intellectual property protection, non-tariff
barriers, cyber intrusions and cyber theft, services,
and agriculture. The two countries agreed to halt the
mutual increase of new tariffs and China undertook
to increase its purchases from the US so as to
“gradually ease the imbalance in two-way
trade”. The official announcement from Beijing was
silent about such purchases, but stated that both
leaders were striving to reach a mutually beneficial
agreement.
On October 17, 2018, the United States
announced its withdrawal from the Universal Postal
Union, in order to renegotiate international shipping
rates for mail and small packages. China had been
paying lower rates because it was considered a
developing nation; the United States intends to
charge the same rates for all countries.
3. 7 Influence of USA-China Trade War on
International Business
3.7. 1 US Executive Branch
The planned Chinese tariffs only amounted to 0.3%
of US GDP. These moves would have “short-term
pain” but “long-term success”. It could be argued
that tariffs are self-defeating and that renegotiating
China's WTO membership [64] would be a more
effective measure. The US economy remained
strong in 2019. Interest rate increases were
necessary to contain inflation. Given this outlook of
strong growth, a strong labor market, and inflation
close to the US goal, and taking account of all the
various risks surrounding this outlook, further
gradual increases are probably the best means of
sustaining economic expansion.
A self-appointed group of billionaires with links
to Goldman Sachs and Wall Street pressed on the
White House, claiming that this was part of a
Chinese government operation that was
undermining the US negotiating position. They
called for foreign agents to be deregistered if found
to be interfering with negotiations or violating the
Foreign Agents Registration Act, urged investment
in factory towns, e.g. Dayton, Ohio, that need a
rebirth of their manufacturing base.
3.7.2 Strong Bipartisan Pushes to Broaden and
Strengthen Sanctions Against China
Democrats, Republicans, Americans of every
political ideology, and every region in the country
should support higher tariffs on China in retaliation
for their country being taken advantage of. Most
Democratic senators, including Committee ranking
members Bob Menendez (Foreign
Relations), Sherrod Brown (Banking), and Ron
Wyden (Finance), called for Americans to confront
the rampant theft of US intellectual property, forced
data storage localization policies, agricultural
policies that disadvantage American farmers, the
dumping shoddy of goods, restricted market access
for US service providers and manufacturers, and
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
184
Volume 1, 2023
mercantilist industrial policies that have cost US
workers their jobs. They called for sanctions on
Chinese companies, such as ZTE, which has
allegedly sold sensitive US technologies to Iran and
North Korea and repeatedly made false statements.
The Democrats have further called for putting
American workers, farmers, businesses, innovation
and national security ahead of China and have
remained steadfast in enforcing US laws against
predatory and abusive behaviors. The Senators have
requested that the administration push harder for
genuine structural reforms in China.
China is a greater threat to American
manufacturing and high-tech industries, and is
heavily involved in industrial espionage. China is
thought to be responsible for 50-80% of cross-border
intellectual property theft worldwide, and over 90%
of cyber-enabled economic espionage in the US.
The US definitely needs to take strong,
intelligently thought out, and strategically effective
action against China’s brazenly unfair trade
practices. However, it needs to do a lot more to
support US workers and products than simply
confront China over its bad behavior. Beijing’s
regulatory barriers, localization requirements, labor
abuses, anti-competitive policies, and many other
unfair trade practices require a full and
comprehensive response. The US has to show moral
courage and be prepared to use its economic
leverage to not only guarantee free trade for
American products in Chinese markets, but also to
advance human rights in China and Tibet.
A brief reduction in the trade deficit did nothing
to solve the main challenges of the trade
relationship. These are going to require “targeted
sanctions” on Chinese companies, non-tariff
restrictions, and upgraded protection for US
intellectual property innovation. US public opinion
remains in favor of revoking China’s most favored
nation status and for waging trade war against that
country.
3.7.3 Markets and Industries
The tariffs had brought about positive and negative
results as early as July 2018. A number of industries
were evincing employment growth while others
were planning layoffs. Stock prices in the US and
China fell significantly four to six weeks prior to the
tariffs going into effect. Trade war fears had led to
a bear market in China. By late June, the country’s
stock market has lost 20% of the value it had the
beginning of 2018 when it reached record levels. The
Japanese Nikkei 225 also suffered a three-
week pullback”. When the tariffs went into effect
(on July 6, 2018), the markets rebounded and rallied
due to a positive jobs report in the US. Asian markets
similarly rebounded, ending the day on a high note.
According to the Associated Press, this positive
response to the tariffs in the US and Asian markets
was due to the end of uncertainty, and according
to Investor’s Business Daily, because the “markets
had largely priced in the impact”.
Announcements of US and Chinese tariff
increases have prompted concerns from several
major US industries. Organizations critical of the
intensifying trade war included the National Pork
Producers Council, the American Soybean
Association, and the Retail Industry Leaders
Association. Several mayors representing towns
with a heavy reliance on manufacturing have also
expressed their concerns. In September, a business
coalition announced a lobbying campaign under the
name of "Tariffs Hurt the Heartland" to protest the
proposed tariffs. Proponents of the increased the US
tariffs included Scott Paul, president of the Alliance
for American Manufacturing.
3.7.4 Increase Protectionism Between the USA
and China
The need to stay afloat on both global and national
markets means that corporations will always look for
ways to protect their profit margins. This obviously
includes avoiding hefty tariffs. The costly price of
building manufacturing infrastructure in the US has
led corporations to turn their eyes toward countries
eager to entice US manufacturing and jobs. Many
companies are already looking to relocate their
manufacturing facilities to China’s neighbor,
Vietnam. The global news magazine, Foreign
Policy, reports that Goertek, a Chinese company that
supplies Apple Air Pods, has already begun
relocating its machines to Vietnam.
This is a decision that many companies will
be forced to make. Coi Rubber President, David
Chao, has stated that he had been
considering offshoring manufacturing to countries
in the proximity of China prior to the trade war talks.
The passage of recent tariff laws only solidified Mr.
Chao’s decision to relocate the company’s China
factory to another competitive country in order to
avoid unreasonable tariff costs and maintain the
company’s global expansion trajectory. Coi Rubber
will continue to operate their three factories in China
but will locate their primary factory in Vietnam.
Although the tariffs may impact many
manufacturers initially, Mr. Chao sees this as an
opportunity to invest in Coi Rubber’s future by
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
185
Volume 1, 2023
building their 4th factory in Vietnam, thereby
allowing them to not only avoid high tariff costs but
to reduce labor costs as well.
The decision of the US administration to
impose a new round of tariff increases on imports
from China has taken the US-China trade dispute to
a new level. Import tariffs were increased 10 p.p.,
and steadily raised to 25 p.p. by the end of 2018. The
new list considerably expanded the range of Chinese
products included in the first two tranches of US
import tariff hikes. These were implemented on July
6 and August 23, 2018. The policy triggered
immediate retaliation. China raised tariffs by 25 p.p.
on similar amounts of imports from the US on the
same dates that the US tariffs came into force.
This sort of protectionist tit-for-tat can have
consequences for the economies of the warring
parties, as the experience of the Great Depression
illustrates [8] [34] [43]. Moreover, it can also affect
third countries, especially those with close economic
ties to the US and China. This paper provides novel
partial equilibrium estimates of the potential trade
and investment impacts of the US-China trade
dispute, focusing on East Asia [14]. Countries in this
region are the most exposed to the dispute by virtue
of their integration with Chinese-led supply chains
and the similarity of their export baskets with that of
China.
We estimate the expected import response to
the tariff increase. To do so we combine HS-8 digit
US import data for 2017 from the US Census Bureau
of Statistics, HS-6 digit product-level price elasticity
of US imports [18][32][37][42][31][35] and the
published lists of Chinese products subject to the
three tranches of US tariffs. We assume the price of
import to increase proportionately with the tariff,
which is then multiplied by the relevant elasticity
and the import value to obtain the expected
reduction in US import from China.
Our calculations suggest that the total US
imports from China in the affected products
amounted to $234.8 billion in 2017, of which $188.9
billion have been targeted in the last tranche of
tariffs (Table 1). Based on the data we use, the
tariffs would reduce US imports from
Table 1: Value of US imports from China targeted
by the tariff measures.
China by $68.6 billion, equivalent to 13.6% of total
US imports from China and 3% of global Chinese
merchandise exports. This expected drop in Chinese
exports would translate into a reduction in domestic
value added by $41.4 billion, a relatively modest
0.3% of Chinese GDP. This is an upper bound of the
direct impact on Chinese exports, as it does not
consider the possible re-direction of these exports
towards third markets.
The bulk of the affected imports is
concentrated in electronic equipment and machinery
and their components (Fig. 3). Electronic and
optical equipment (including TV and sound
Fig. 3: Expected drop in US imports from China due
to US tariffs hike, by HS-2 digit sector ($ million).
recording devices) and their components,
machinery, boilers and mechanical appliances
account for almost half of the expected drop in US
imports from China. A significant amount of the
import drop is also expected in consumer products,
such as furniture, vehicles, leather articles and fish
and crustaceans, which may have some direct impact
on parts of the typical US household consumption
basket.
The upside of the reduction in Chinese
exports to the US is the potential diversion of US
imports towards non-Chinese suppliers, particularly
in East Asia, where export structures are similar to
the Chinese ones. The present study identifies
Chinese products (at the HS-8 digit level) that are
subject to higher tariffs in the US, and which other
East Asian countries exported to the US in 2017 in
order to give a sense of these potential export
opportunities. It seems probable that a country that
is exporting a non-negligible amount of a certain
product to a certain market would be more likely to
replace an existing exporter in that product-market
pair [38].
According to this metric, the replacement
potential of Chinese exports in the US by East Asian
countries especially emerging economies is quite
significant. Vietnam, the Philippines, and Cambodia
are the East Asian countries with the largest
replacement potential relative to the size of their
economy (Fig. 4). The estimated drop in Chinese
exports to the US
Fig. 4: Potential replacement of Chinese exports to
the US, by countries (% of GDP).
(at values of at least 10 mln USD) is equivalent to
10.9% of Vietnam’s GDP. This falls to 4.4% when
the associated domestic value added of these exports
is considered. The greatest opportunities lie in those
products for which the expected drop in Chinese
exports to the US (and which Vietnam already
exports there) are large, e.g. chairs, insulated
ignition, shrimp and prawns, travel bags, seat parts,
television cameras, wooden furniture, and handbags
(Fig. 5).
Fig. 5: Main potential products where Vietnam
could replace Chinese exports in the US.
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
186
Volume 1, 2023
Cambodia exports a much smaller set of products
with these characteristics, e.g. plywood sheets,
handbags, travel and sports bags, lighting sets for
Christmas trees, dog and cat food, seat parts, and
bicycles. Taiwan [51], Singapore, Malaysia, and
Thailand also have non-negligible export
replacement potential. The potential replacement is
more limited for Indonesia. The drop of Chinese
gross exports to the US in products that Indonesia
also exports there is equivalent to 1.3% of GDP, with
an associated domestic value added of 1.0% of GDP
[38].
By raising the cost of serving the US market
from China, the trade war could also divert
investment to third countries [14]. This diversion is
most likely to affect investment seeking to by-pass
US import tariff hikes. The extent to which
investment intended to serve the US market can
relocate to other countries partly depends on each
country’s ability to produce the same set of affected
products and partly on perceptions about the
duration of the trade war. The present study
measures this ability through the correlation index
between the expected drop in US imports from
China and US imports from each East Asian country
in those HS 8-digit products subject to the tariffs
[38]. The value of the index is highest for Taiwan,
followed by Thailand, Malaysia, Vietnam, and the
Philippines, and lowest for Indonesia and Myanmar
(Fig. 6).
Fig. 6: Degree of similarities of export baskets to the
US with China for affected products (index of
correlation at HS-8 digit).
While this ranking tries to capture only one of the
several criteria used for investment choices, it is
suggestive of the variation in relative attractiveness
across potential destinations for investments based
on an export basket similar to that of China [38].
While China has progressively absorbed large
chunks of the value chain in various sectors [19][29],
it still relies on imports of foreign intermediates and
final inputs for some of its production. East Asian
countries are key suppliers of such intermediates and
inputs to China [14]. Hence, the expected drop in
Chinese exports to the US may have knock-on
effects on these countries via backward linkages.
The extent of this impact would depend on which
parts of the value chain each country contributes to.
This in turn determines the intermediates and raw
materials that other countries provide to China in the
production of the products affected by the tariff hike
[38].
In order to gauge the importance of this
channel, the estimated drop in Chinese exports at the
HS-8 digit level is matched with the country-specific
shares of domestic value added in Chinese gross
exports to the US in those products (available from
OECD TiVA data). Taiwan and Malaysia are the
East Asian countries [51] that appear most vulnerable
to the drop in Chinese exports via the supply chain
with an estimated GDP loss of 0.24% and 0.20%
respectively [38] (Fig. 7).
Fig. 7: Estimated effects of US-China trade war on
GDP via supply linkages.
This is mainly due to the fact that they provide inputs
for Chinese exports to the US in electronic and
optical equipment, as well as electrical machinery,
which accounts for two third of this loss. Singapore,
South Korea, and Thailand are all expected to lose
more than 0.1% of their GDP via this channel, while
the results for Cambodia, Indonesia and Vietnam are
relatively muted due to the low participation in
Chinese-led global value chains [14].
While these negative effects are smaller than
the estimated (positive) export replacement
potential, the two figures are not necessarily
comparable. The latter are upper bound estimates of
the potential for replacement. The true dimension of
the replacement effect is likely to be considerably
smaller for two reasons: first, each country would be
competing for the same potential market; second,
any such replacement would hinge on the supply
response in each country-product pair, which could
be relatively small (and even zero) in many cases.
By contrast, the effects via the supply chain are
likely to provide a more precise order of magnitude
of the actual losses [38][36].
This type of analysis could help policymakers
in East Asia (and beyond) identify the potential
winners and losers among domestic producers from
the US-China trade war [14]. Governments could
help the former replace Chinese exports to the US
through measures such as facilitating access to
imported inputs, which are heavily used by East
Asian exporters, and ensuring the availability of the
finance, including trade finance, that will be required
for the additional production and exports [38]; [36].
At the same time, assistance to potential losers to
reallocate their production and/or their labor could
help minimize the domestic costs of the trade war
[6].
3.7.5 China in a Trade War with the USA and
its other Trading Partners
The US Administration deserves credit for taking a
harder line towards Beijing, both at home and
abroad. Attacking Chinese protectionism [29][30]
now has bipartisan support in Washington and
Berlin, and in 2018, the United Kingdom joined the
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
187
Volume 1, 2023
United States in imposing tighter restrictions on
Chinese investment. But their critics claim that they
have not done enough to capitalize on those shared
grievances. If anything, they have achieved the
reverse. For example, in 2018, they alienated
European and Japanese officials by imposing tariffs
on their steel and aluminum to the US.
China has tried to defuse the global irritation
over its mercantilist stance by signaling a
willingness to revise its “Made in China 2025”
program of state subsidies and market share targets.
This recent flexibility comes as Chinese industrial
production figures at the end 2018 year fell short of
economists’ expectations and retail sales were
growing at their slowest rate in 15 years. Analysts in
China and the United States say China is modifying
the “Made in China” program because of pressure
from all its major trading partners.
The US Trade Representative Robert E.
Lighthizer has claimed that this subsidy program,
which sets market share goals for Chinese industry,
imperils US technological hegemony. China wants
its semiconductor manufacturers to provide 70% of
domestic needs, up from less than 20% today. At
stake are 6 bln USD in annual US exports.
But roughly a dozen other countries are even more
dependent on high-tech manufacturing and exports
of advanced factory gear, and are more exposed to
China’s desire to replace purchases of foreign
products with domestic alternatives, according to the
Mercator Institute for China Studies in Berlin.
The pushback from other trading partners is
a crucial factor in the dynamic development of
China. That’s because the Made in China 2025
program is more of a threat to Germany, South
Korea and Japan than it is to the United States.
External pressure drove China to open markets for
financial services and automobiles, according to
economist Andrew Polk, a partner in Trivium China,
a Beijing-based consultancy.
At the end of 2018, the EU agreed to establish
a new foreign investment screening mechanism.
This initiative was largely motivated by a sharp
increase in Chinese activity on the continent
[30][39]. However, it leaves final decisions to
national governments. As such, it is less effective
than the Committee on Foreign Investment in the
United States. The German government blocked two
potential acquisitions by Chinese investors in July
2018. This came on the heels of similar action by
Canada two months earlier. Germany also lowered
the level of foreign ownership that requires
government review from 25% to 15%.
With the United States and China locked in a
geopolitical competition, it is easier for revision-
minded officials to advocate changes in programs
like Made in China 2025 by citing shared concerns
among the country’s major trading partners. The
Chinese authorities have changed course under
pressure before. In 2015, they scrapped plans to
require foreign financial institutions to install
Chinese software after complaints from US,
European and Japanese diplomats and business
groups. Some administration officials scoff at the
proposed changes as being cosmetic and designed to
sap US negotiating resolve. Michael Wessel, a
member of the US-China Economic and Security
Review Commission, described the plans to allow
foreign companies a greater role in the Chinese
technology program were “an influence operation at
its best”. He also questioned whether Chinese laws
would mean much so long as the courts remained
under the control of the Communist Party. “What the
Chinese are talking about are really just baby steps”,
he said [23].
On June 1, 2018, following similar action by
the US, the EU initiated legal proceedings against
China in the WTO, alleging that by compelling
foreign firms to grant ownership and usage rights of
their technology to Chinese entities, China was
discriminating against foreign firms and
undermining the intellectual property rights of EU
companies [30][39]. EU firms were allegedly forced
to establish joint ventures as a precondition for
gaining access to the Chinese market. The European
Commissioner for Trade, Cecilia Malmström, said
“We cannot let any country force our companies to
surrender this hard-earned knowledge at its border”.
This is against international rules that we have all
agreed upon in the WTO. American, European and
Japanese officials have discussed joint strategy and
taken actions against unfair competition by China
[30]. The 2018 G20 Summit in Buenos Aires
concluded the multilateral trading system “is
currently falling short of its objectives ... necessary
reform of the WTO to improve its functioning” [44]
[30].
4 Conclusions
Foreign trade policy plays a key role in the
maintenance of both economic and political
liberalization. Rent seeking can have far-reaching
implications for a country’s economic development.
This is especially true in underdeveloped and
transitional countries, where it can take scarce
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
188
Volume 1, 2023
resources from productive areas and use them to
promote and/or perpetuate rents.
Structural and micro-political economy
analyses of foreign trade policy in the context of
sustainable development invariably fail to factor in
the impact of the recent reappraisals of
protectionism and the relatively fixed nature of the
institutions designed to handle domestic producer
complaints. The political consensus on foreign trade
policy and protectionism has changed over time.
Tariffs and other forms of protectionism assume
greater prominence in the policies of political parties
during a recession. However, even during a
recession, there is usually a modicum of support for
a liberal foreign trade policy in a market economy.
No foreign trade policy is purely liberal or purely
protectionist. Foreign trade policy tends towards
liberalism during periods of rapid economic growth
and protectionism during downturns.
A tariff trade war will inflict considerable
harm on China in all indicators, including welfare,
GDP, manufacturing employment, and trade.
However, China should nevertheless be able to
sustain the costs, and its economy should not be
severely damaged. As for the United States, the
simulation predicts it will gain on welfare, GDP and
non-manufacturing production, but lose on
employment and trade (both export and import). As
these are by far the two largest economies on the
planet, their actions inevitably affect the entire
world. The simulation therefore predicts that the rest
of the world will feel the impact of any trade war
between them.
Most large and developed nations will benefit
from a US-China trade war. As trade decreases
between the United States and China, it will
presumably increase between other nations. For
example, Chinese and international rubber
producers are preparing to restructure their supply
chains by relocating their manufacturing facilities
from China to Vietnam and Malaysia. However,
smaller nations will see significant negative impacts.
For example, the world’s total welfare, GDP,
manufacturing production and employment, export,
import, and total trade are expected to decrease since
many of these nations are highly trade dependent.
China is not merely romanticizing its historical
legacies; there are painstaking economic and
geopolitical calculations underpinning its strategies
for the 21st century. It is important to pay heed to
changing trends in the international trade regime.
Commercial relations are too important to be held
hostage to political grandstanding or airy rhetoric
from politicians performing for domestic galleries.
Disturbing these relations would have ramifications
for sales, growth, and employment especially in
this day and age of COVID-19 [36]. Commercial
imperatives can pose political dilemmas for
autocratic regimes such as China. Again, this applies
a fortiori with respect to the COVID -19 pandemic
[36].
The Global Financial Crisis of 2007–2008
(GFC) was a total shock to the comparison in cost
savings. Global supply chains became more costly
when the risk of a non-delivery of an input good
increased substantially after the Global Crisis. Firms
may have also expected higher tariff rates after the
Global Crisis, which shrinks advantage of GVCs as
input goods pass the border several times. At the
same time, the Global Crisis made robot adoption
less costly, with the sharp decline in interest rates
relative to wages when central banks started to fight
the adverse effect of the crisis. As a result, many
firms in rich countries like USA started to re-shore
production back to their home country and invested
in robots instead.
In the wake of the Global Crisis, uncertainty in
the world economy led many firms to reassess their
business models. Rather than relying on global
supply chains, an increasing number of firms
invested in robots, which prompted a renaissance of
manufacturing in industrialized countries like USA.
Changes in the world economy due to COVID-19
make a V-shaped recovery from the coming
recession unlikely, more likely is U and in services
L. Instead, COVID-19 will accelerate the process
begun after the Global Crisis by encouraging firms
to re-shore activity back to rich countries like USA
[36].
A great deal has depended on the attitude of the
US and its allies during the conflict between Russia
and Ukraine. Unless they agree to a compromise,
paid for by Ukraine, this will be a long-drawn-out
guerrilla war. The conflict with the West, which has
already moved into the military phase in Ukraine,
and which will continue to be played out in parallel
in the political, diplomatic, media, economic and
virtual worlds (hacking attacks have been ongoing
for a long time and show no sign of letting up), could
eventually exhaust Russia’s forces and deplete its
resources. If this scenario came to pass, Russia
might well be plunged into an economic crisis
comparable that which afflicted the USSR during its
final days.
In this context, the world economy has entered
a phase of geopolitical turbulence that will have
enormous economic and financial consequences far
beyond Ukraine. A hot war between the major
powers sometime in the next ten years is on the
cards. Price shocks will have a negative impact
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
189
Volume 1, 2023
worldwide, especially on poorer households, as food
and fuel account for a higher percentage of their
expenditure. If the conflict escalates, the damage to
the world economy will be even more devastating.
The sanctions imposed on Russia will have a
significant impact on the global economy and
financial markets, and significantly poison other
countries. The monetary authorities will need to
carefully monitor the spillover of rising international
prices onto local inflation in order to prepare the
right responses. State fiscal policies will have to
support the most vulnerable households to
counterbalance the rising cost of living.
References:
[1] Alt, J. E., Gilligan, M. J. The Political Economy
of Trading States, Journal of Political Philosophy,
2, 1994, pp. 165–192. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-
0531(77)90135-1.
[2] Alt, J. E., Frieden, J., Gilligan, M. J., Rodrik, D.,
Rogowski, R., The Political Economy of
International Trade: Enduring Puzzles and an
Agenda for Inquiry, Comparative Political Studies,
29, 1996, pp. 689–717.
https://doi.org/10.1162/002081802320005478.
[3] Anderson, K., Lobbying Incentives and the
Pattern of Protection in Rich and Poor Countries,
Economic Development and Cultural Change, 43,
1995, 401–423. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-
46925-0.
[4] Baldwin, R., WTO 2.0. Global governance of
supply chain trade. Policy Insight, 64 2012,
https://doi.org/10.1002/sres.2148.
[5] Banerji, A., Ghanem H., Does the Type of
Political Regime Matter for Trade and Labor Market
Policies?. The World Bank Economic Review, 11.
1997, https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lht011.
[6] Calì, M., The impact of the US-China trade war
on East Asia, 16 October 2018,
https://voxeu.org/article/impact-us-china-trade-war-
east-asia (accessed: 4.01.2019).
[7] Coleman, W. D., From Protected Development
to Market Liberalism. Paradigm Change in
Agriculture. Journal of European Public Policy, 5,
1998, pp. 632–651.
[8] Eichengreen, B., Irwin, D., The Slide to
Protectionism in the Great Depression: Who
Succumbed and Why?. The Journal of Economic
History, 70(4), 2010, pp. 871–
897.https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050718000219.
[9] Frey, B. S., The public Choice View of
International Political Economy. International
Organization, 38, 1984, pp.199–223.
https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/TVMFQ.
[10]Frey, B. S., Pommerehne W., Schneider, F.,
Gilbert, G., Consensus and Dis consensus among
Economists: An Empirical Inquiry. American
Economic Review, 74, 1984, pp. 986–994.
https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.108.63.
[11] Frieden, J., Debt, Development and
Democracy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
1991.
[12] Frieden, J., Rogowski, R., The Impact of
International Economy on National Policies: An
Intellectual Overview. In: R. O. Keohane, H. V.
Milner (Eds), Internationalization and Domestic
Politics (p. 1–318). Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press. 1996.
[13] Grossman, G., Helpman, E. Protection for Sale.
American Economic Review, 84(4) 1994..
https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.108.63.
[14] Guangyuan, L., Pogłębianie reform i rozwoju w
Chinach okazja dla całego świata 2020/06/11,
http://www.chinaembassy.org.pl/pol/dsxx/dshd/t17
87958.htm (accessed: 9.01.2022).
[15] Jackson, R. J., Global politics in the 21st
century. New York: Cambridge University Press.
2013.
[16] Jones, K., Reconstructing the World Trade
Organization for 21st century, an institutional
approach. Oxford, New York: Oxford University
Press. 2015.
[17] Jupill, W. M., Snidal, D., Institutional choice
and global commerce. New York: Cambridge
University Press. 2013.
[18] Kee, H. L., Nicita, A., Olarreaga, M.. Import
Demand Elasticities and Trade Distortions. The
Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4), 2008, pp.
666–682. https://doi.org/10.2307/1925884.
[19] Kee H. L., Tang, H., Domestic Value Added in
Exports: Theory and Firm Evidence from China.
American Economic Review, 106(6), 2016, pp.
1402–1436. https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.108.63.
[20] Krist, W. , Globalization and America’s trade
agreements. Baltimore: John Hopkins University
Press. 2013.
[21]Krugman, P., Increasing returns and economic
geography. Massachusetts Institute of Technology,
1991.
[22] Kupchan, C. A., Unpacking hegemony: the
social foundations of hierarchical order. In: G. J.
Ikenberry (ed.), Power, order, and change in world
politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
2014.
[23] Lynch, D. J., Trump, a global loner, finds his
China trade war complaints draw a crowd, 2018,
December 14,
https://web.archiv.org/web/20181217112227/,
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
190
Volume 1, 2023
https://www.washgingtonpost.com/people/david-j-
lynch (accessed: 04.01.2019).
[24] Magee, S. P., Brock, W. A., Young, L., Black
Hole Tariffs and Endogenous Policy Theory
Political Economy in General Equilibrium.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1989.
[25] Nau, H. R., Domestic Trade Politics and the
Uruguay Round: An Overview. In: H. R. Nau (eds.),
Domestic Trade Politics and the Uruguay Round
(pp. XVII, 216). New York: Columbia University
Press, 1989.
[26] Nelson, D., Endogenous Tariff Theory: A
Critical Review. American Journal of Political
Science, 32, 1988, pp. 796–837.
https://doi.org/10.1111.
[27] Olson, M. , Space, Agriculture and
Organization. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, 67, 1985, pp. 928–937.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1237296.
[28] Olson, M., The Exploitation and Subsidization
of Agriculture in Developing and Developed
Countries. In: A. Maunder, U. Renborg (eds.),
Agriculture in a Turbulent World Economy. Gower,
U.K.: Aldershot. 1986.
[29] Puślecki, Z. W., European Union-China. Trade
Relationships. Warsaw: Publishing House
CeDeWu. 2018a.
[30] Puślecki, Z. W., Handel zagraniczny.
Transformacja biznesu międzynarodowego.
Warszawa: PWN, 2021a.
[31]Puślecki, Z. W., International Business Theory
and International Economy. Saarbruecken: LAP
LAMBERT Academic Publishing is a trademark of
OmniScriptum GmbH&Co. KG, 2013.
[32] Puślecki, Z. W., Les tendences contemporaines
du protectionnisme non tarifaire. Polish Western
Affairs/LaPologne et les Affaires Occidentales, 1,
1984, pp. 32–82.
https://doi.org/10.4000/belgeo.12138.
[33] Puślecki, Z. W., Mercantilist Tendencies in
Contemporary Foreign Trade Policy
Journal of Global Change and
Governance, 1(4), 2008, pp. 1–11.
https://doi.org/pp.2016.21.4.13.
[34] Puślecki, Z. W., New Tendency in
Contemporary Foreign Trade Policy. Journal of
Economics, Management and Trade, 25(3), 2019a,
https://doi.org/10.9734/BJEMT/2015/19269.
[35] Puślecki, Z. W. Non-Governmental
Organizations and the Liberalization of Global
Trade Policy Under GATT/WTO. In: H. M. Hensel
(ed.), The United States and Europe: Policy
Imperative in a Globalizing World (p. 183–204).
Burlington: Ashgate Publishing Ltd, Aldershot.
2002.
[36] Puślecki, Z. W. , Structural Modifications of
International Business Theory and Policy in the
Time of Covid-19. American Journal of
Management, 23(3), 2023.
https://doi.org/10.33423/ajm.v23i3.6425.
[37] Puślecki, Z. W., System środków kontroli
handlowej Unii Europejskiej w warunkach
globalizacji. Poznań: Scientific Publishing House
UAM, 2001.
[38] Puślecki, Z. W., Świat we mgle. Modyfikacje
strukturalne w gospodarce światowej po pandemii
COVID-19 i wojnie Rosji z Ukrainą. Berlin:
GlobeEdit, Chisinau 2022.
[39] Puślecki, Z. W., Światowa Organizacja Handlu
i Unia Europejska wobec wyzwań we współczesnym
biznesie międzynarodowym. Warsaw: Publishing
House C.H. Beck, 2021b
[40] Puślecki, Z. W., The Need to Establish a New
Format for Trade Political Relations Between
European Union and China. Warsaw: Publishing
House CeDeWu, 2020a
[41] Puślecki, Z. W. ,
The Impact of Increasing
Global Supply Chains on the Foreign Trade Policy.
Journal of International Research in Economics and
Finance, 1(1), 2018b, pp. 79–100.
https://doi.org/10.20849/iref.v2i1.310.
[42] Puślecki, Z. W., Trade conflicts during
the multilateral negotiations on the international
trade liberalization In: S. Nagel (ed.), Policymaking
and Prosperity: A Multinational Anthology.
Lanham/Boulder/New York/Oxford: Lexington
Books, 2003
[43] Puślecki, Z. W., Trends Reshaping
International Business Theory and Policy. Warsaw:
Publishing House ELIPSA, 2019b.
[44] Puślecki, Z. W., World Economy Against New
Challenges in the Time of COVID-19. Warsaw:
Publishing House ELIPSA, 2020b.
[45] Rodrik, D., Political Economy of Trade Policy.
In: G. Grossman, K. Rogoff (Eds), Handbook of
International Economics, vol. 3 (p. 1457–1494).
Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.1995.
[46] Rogowski, R. , Commerce and Coalitions.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 1989
[47] Rogowski, R.., Political Cleavages and
Changing Exposures to Trade. American Political
Science Review, 81, 1987a, pp. 1121–1137.
https://doi.org/10.2307/196258.
[48] Rogowski, R., Trade and the Variety of
Democratic Institutions. International
Organization, 41, 1987b, pp. 203–222.
https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/TVMFQ.
[49] Sheingate, A. D., The Rise of Agricultural
Welfare State: Institutions and Interests Group
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
191
Volume 1, 2023
Power in the United States, France, and Japan.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 2001.
[50] Thies, C. G., Porche, S., Crawfish Tails: A
Curious Tale of Foreign Trade Policy Making.
Foreign Policy Analysis, 3, 2007, pp. 171–187.
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1743-8594.2007.00046.x.
[51] Zhang J., . Chin i Stanów Zjednoczonych wojna o chipy.
A w tle przyszłość światowej gospodarki, 2021
https://wiadomosci.onet.pl/opinie/chin-i-stanow-
zjednoczonych-wojna-o-chipy-a-w-tle-przyszlosc-
swiatowej-gospodarki/mgqdskn [accessed:
18.02.2021].
Contribution of Individual Authors to the
Creation of a Scientific Article (Ghostwriting
Policy)
The author equally contributed in the present
research, at all stages from the formulation of the
problem to the final findings and solution.
Sources of Funding for Research Presented in a
Scientific Article or Scientific Article Itself
No funding was received for conducting this study.
Conflict of Interest
The author have no conflicts of interest to declare
that are relevant to the content of this article.
Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0
(Attribution 4.0 International, CC BY 4.0)
This article is published under the terms of the
Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0
https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/deed.e
n US
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
192
Volume 1, 2023
Figures and Table
Fig. 1: The rapidly increasing US trade imbalance with China.
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
193
Volume 1, 2023
Fig. 2: US Trade Representative.
Table 1: Value of US imports from China targeted by the tariff measures.
Source: M. Calì, The impact of the US-China trade war on East Asia, 16 October 2018,
https://voxeu.org/article/impact-us-china-trade-war-east-asia, 4.01.2019.
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
194
Volume 1, 2023
Fig. 3: Expected drop in US imports from China due to US tariffs hike, by HS-2 digit sector ($ million).
Fig. 4: Potential replacement of Chinese exports to the US, by countries (% of GDP).
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
195
Volume 1, 2023
Fig. 5: Main potential products where Vietnam could replace Chinese exports in the US.
Fig. 6: Degree of similarities of export baskets to the US with China for affected products (index of correlation
at HS-8 digit).
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
196
Volume 1, 2023
Fig. 7: Estimated effects of US-China trade war on GDP via supply linkages.
International Journal of Environmental Engineering and Development
DOI: 10.37394/232033.2023.1.19
Zdzisław W. Puślecki
E-ISSN: 2945-1159
197
Volume 1, 2023