Production Diversification as a Tool for Agricultural Risk
Management: The Case of Northern Kazakhstan
TALGAT KUSSAIYNOV, GULNARA MUSSINA, SANDUGASH TOKENOVA,
SALTANAT MAMBETOVA
Saken Seifullin Kazakh Agro-Technical Research University,
Astana,
REPUBLIC OF KAZAKHSTAN
Abstract:- This paper addresses the impacts of degree of risk aversion on optimal farm plans in Kazakh
agriculture. The results obtained during the field research in the region of Northern Kazakhstan are presented.
Calculations were carried out using data from 145 peasant farms in the region for 2017-2022 based on a risk
model. It has been found that the choice of a portfolio is influenced not only by considerations of profitability
and riskiness of crops, but also by grain production traditions deeply rooted among the farmers of the region,
and the skills and knowledge associated with them, as well as the existing infrastructure. These circumstances
constrain the wider spread of oilseed crops in the region. It seems that the size of the farm does not significantly
affect the choice of portfolio, while the degree of risk aversion by the farmer affects the optimal farming plan.
The potential benefits of the farming diversification are an empirical issue, and it should be addressed on a
case-by-case basis. The question is to choose the utility function and its parameters that most accurately reflect
the preferences of a particular farmer, the authors conclude.
Key-Words: - uncertainty; diversification; crop production; income; covariance; model; decision making; risk
aversion; utility function; optimization.
Received: May 2, 2023. Revised: October 11, 2023. Accepted: October 23, 2023. Published: November 3, 2023.
1 Introduction
There is always a trade-off between diversification
and specialization. Farm planning models to find
the most referable degree of production
diversification is usually cast in the portfolio
selection framework. And the best approach is to
formulate the model in terms of direct expected
utility maximization. This type of models puts
more weight on bad outcomes and is more
consistent with the expected utility hypothesis. In
countries such as Kazakhstan, where risk-sharing
strategies have not yet become widespread, on-
farm management strategies can more readily be
used to soften the impact of downside risk. The
idea of diversification is to reduce the dispersion of
the overall return by selecting a mixture of
activities that have net returns with low or negative
correlations. Again, however, the aim should be to
find the risk-efficient combinations of activities,
not the one that merely minimizes variance. In
general, farmers will diversify more with an
increasing degree of risk aversion. However, more
diversification can be increasingly costly if it
means forgoing the advantages that specialization
confers
through better command of superior technologies
and closer attention to the special needs of one
particular market. And diversification remains a
priority on the farm to prevent or mitigate the
consequences of undesirable events (risk
reduction). Of course, they may also include
measures reflecting risk aversion on the part of the
decision-maker.
The paper is organized as follows. The next
section describes the data and methods. Then the
results are presented. The final section provides a
discussion of the results and concluding remarks.
In recent years, a number of studies have
documented how farmers in different countries are
adopting measures that rely on the use of
agricultural biodiversity in response to climatic
changes and their associated effects, [1], [2], [3],
[4], [5]. These measures can be classified in three
categories: cultivation of a larger number of
species and farm diversification overall;
introduction or increased cultivation of better
adapted crops and varieties, and livestock animals
and breeds; and integration of trees and shrubs into
production systems. Different crops are affected
differently by climate events, and this in turn gives
some minimum assured returns for livelihood
WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on BUSINESS and ECONOMICS
DOI: 10.37394/23207.2023.20.210
Talgat Kussaiynov, Gulnara Mussina,
Sandugash Tokenova, Saltanat Mambetova
E-ISSN: 2224-2899
2457
Volume 20, 2023
security. Alternating cereal crops with legumes has
been a common practice for maintaining soil
nutrients, managing diseases and adapting crop
production to climatic variations that has been
widely successful, [6].
The introduction of livestock has also been
observed as a diversification strategy in response
to climate change, [7], [8]. Over the past three
decades, in many arid regions of Kazakhstan
farmers have reduced their investment in crops, or
even stop planting and focus instead on livestock
management. Different animal species and breeds
differ greatly in the extent to which they can
tolerate climatic extremes. In arid areas of
Kazakhstan, there has been a return to the breeding
of traditional animals for commercial purposes,
such as camel, sheep and horse breeding, more
adapted to the changing climatic conditions. Such
trends take place almost everywhere. For example,
[9], notices the expansion of the distribution range
of one-humped camels further south in Africa,
replacing cattle, because of their better drought
resistance. Crop diversification and crop-livestock
integration are often combined with adjustments in
agricultural practices and adoption of low-input
methods for soil fertility improvement, water
conservation and weed management. The
substitution of traditional varieties with improved,
early maturing ones has also been observed as part
of adaptation strategies in places affected by
drastic increases or decreases of temperature and
rainfall, [10], [11]. The opposite is also observed:
farmers stick to the cultivation of traditional
varieties because of their capacity to respond and
adapt to new climate patterns, [12].
The most important role in ensuring success in
farming is played by competent risk-based
planning. In a planning model accounting for
uncertainty it is usually important to take account
of the farmers' risk attitude. In countries with
transition economy, such as Kazakhstan, many
previous studies assumed complete certainty or
overlooked farmers' aversion to risk. Others who
have incorporated farmers' risk attitudes have
found risk aversion to have an important influence
on the choice of the farming plan.
Our empirical objectives are to examine the
effect on the optimal farm plan of differences in
(1) farm size, (2) farmers' risk aversion.
2 Methods and Data
A realistic planning model should take into
account the farmer's subjective assessment of the
probability of the occurrence of uncertain
consequences from the decisions made and his
preferences regarding these consequences,
reflecting the farmer’s degree of risk aversion. It is
assumed that the subjective expected utility
hypothesis is the best framework for structuring
these two components into a workable model of
risky choice, [13].
As a utility function, we used a power function
of the form 󰇡
󰇢, where is size of
wealth (the value of assets), is coefficient of
relative risk aversion. This function is useful for
solving problems and interpreting their results. In
r=0 this case, the function takes a linear form
; the linear function corresponds to the case when
the entrepreneur's attitude to risk is neutral (risk is
not taken into account when optimizing the
solution). When r=1 the power function turns into
a logarithmic one. The higher the value r, the less
likely the entrepreneur is to make risky decisions,
so the less willing they are to invest in risky
activities. The study, [14], offers the following
interpretation of the coefficients of risk aversion:
󰇛󰇜 is individual manifests an indifference
to risk (in other words, assess risky decision only
on subjective expected impact); 󰇛󰇜  is
perhaps taking the risk into account; 󰇛󰇜 is
paying attention to a reasonable degree; 󰇛󰇜
is very cautiously accepts the risk; 󰇛󰇜 is
high level of risk prevention; 󰇛󰇜 is
extremely high degree of risk aversion. Nobel
Prize winner in economics, [15], suggests
considering the relative coefficient of risk aversion
equal to one as "normal", which is typical for most
individuals. We note that in most cases the risk
aversion coefficient is estimated in relation to the
total wealth of the enterprise, so the total value of
its assets. In practice, to make a decision, the main
argument of the utility function, as a rule, is
income, that is, the increase in the value of assets.
In this regard, there is a need to recalculate the
relative coefficient of risk aversion for income.
The recalculation is carried out with the use of a
formula that relates the coefficients of income and
risk aversion by wealth:
󰇛󰇜 󰇡
󰇢󰇛󰇜 (1)
whereis the average annual income; is the
average annual total asset value of the enterprise.
In our problem, risk aversion was estimated by
the ratio of marginal income. At r=0, the risk is
not considered when optimizing the solution. As
the coefficient r increases, the entrepreneur avoids
making risky decisions of the production structure.
WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on BUSINESS and ECONOMICS
DOI: 10.37394/23207.2023.20.210
Talgat Kussaiynov, Gulnara Mussina,
Sandugash Tokenova, Saltanat Mambetova
E-ISSN: 2224-2899
2458
Volume 20, 2023
The following model has been used to solve the
problem:
 󰇛󰇜󰇛󰇜
󰇛󰇜 (2)
under restrictions:
1) use of resources
  
 󰇛󰇜
 (4)
2) the share of the area of individual crops is
the maximum allowable in the structure of crops
  (5)
3) fulfillment of contractual obligations for the
supply of individual products or by market
capacity 󰇛󰇜  (6)
4) market conditions and margin income based
on production

  󰇛󰇜
5) the minimum required income for fulfillment
of financial obligations in any state of production
and market conditions, for example, to repay a loan
  (8)
6) margin income expected
󰇛󰇜

7) utility expected
󰇛󰇜 󰇛󰇜

󰇛󰇜
󰇛󰇜

where:  is the guaranteed equivalent; 󰇛󰇜 is
the expected utility; is a coefficient of relative
risk aversion; is an index of the resource ( =1 is
the index of arable land); is an index of crop; is
an index of market conditions and production;
is number of species of economic resources; is a
quantity of types of crops; is a set of states of
production and market conditions; is a set of
crops (products); is the area under the j-crop; 
is the cost of resource i per one hectare of crop j;
is the total size of resources i used ( is the
total area of arable land under crops); is the
overall size of resources i available on the farm;
is the maximum share of the area under crop j;
is the yield of crop j; is the market capacity or
the amount of contractual commitments for the
supply of product j;  is the margin income per
hectare of crop j in state s of production and
market conditions; is the total size of the margin
income from crops in state s of production and
market conditions; is the minimum amount of
whole-farm margin income required under any
production and market conditions; is the total
expected whole-farm margin income; is the
probability of state s of production and market
conditions.
Calculations were carried out using data from
145 farms of North-Kazakhstan region for 2017-
2022. Farms were divided into 6 groups according
to the size of the arable land. Then the average
farm size for each group was determined. Further
calculations based on the model were carried out
on average farms. The main constraints in the
model are (1) land constraint, (2) rotational limits
(to avoid the build-up of pests and diseases it is
assumed that no more than a quarter of the area can
be oilseeds).
Farms under consideration grow crops such as
wheat, barley, oats, buckwheat, peas, rapeseed for
seeds and flax. The size of acreage in farms ranges
from 16 to 3082 hectares. The first group consisted
of 19 farms (with crop area 16 to 49 hectares), the
second group includes 37 farms (with crop area 50
to 125 hectares), the third group comprises 43
farms (with crop area 126 to 344 hectares, the
fourth group includes 25 farms with a sown area of
345 to 799 hectares, the fifth group consisted of 14
farms (with crop area 800 to 1734 ha), 7 farms
make up the sixth group with crop area of 1735
and more hectares. Table 1 (Appendix) shows
marginal income by crops on the farms for the
period from 2017 to 2022.
3 Results and Discussion
In all groups of farms, oilseeds are the dominant
crops in terms of economic efficiency. Flax is
represented in each group, while rapeseed only in
the 5th group of farms. It should be borne in mind
that the most stable is the income from oilseeds.
Peas on the farms of the 1st and 4th groups have
the lowest efficiency in terms of income, barley in
the 2nd group of farms, oats in groups 3 and 6. At
the same time, peas turn out to be the most
economically risky crop, while other crops occupy
an intermediate position in terms of variability.
These circumstances, of course, have a decisive
influence on the processes of structural
optimization of production.
Table 2 (Appendix) shows the results of
optimizing the production structure based on
model (2)-(11). The economic conditions of each
year are assumed to be equally probable, namely,
the probability of each of them is 0.17.
WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on BUSINESS and ECONOMICS
DOI: 10.37394/23207.2023.20.210
Talgat Kussaiynov, Gulnara Mussina,
Sandugash Tokenova, Saltanat Mambetova
E-ISSN: 2224-2899
2459
Volume 20, 2023
The results of calculations show that in the
farms of the 1st group, with an indifferent attitude
to risk (the risk aversion coefficient is zero), wheat
(75.0%) and flax (25.0%) are included in the
production structure. The expected margin income
per 1 hectare is 75.5 thousand tenge, the variability
is 47.0%. As the coefficient of relative risk
aversion increases (the entrepreneur is more
careful when making a decision), the share of
wheat decreases, and barley is included in the
structure. With a "normal" degree of risk aversion
characteristic of most entrepreneurs (in the
conditions of the problem, this corresponds to a
coefficient of relative risk aversion for marginal
income of 0.3), the shares of wheat, barley, and
flax are 66.9%, 8.1%, and 25.0%, respectively. The
expected marginal income per 1 ha is 75.4
thousand tenge with a variability of 46.6%. In case
of risk aversion with a coefficient of 0.6 or higher,
barley (75.0%) and flax (25.0%) remain in the
optimal production plan, and wheat is excluded.
On the farms of the 2nd group, the optimal
sowing plan includes wheat, peas and flax with any
attitude to risk. The change in the value of the risk
aversion coefficient affects the ratio of the share of
these crops in the plan. In the case when the value
of the risk coefficient is zero, wheat, peas and flax
occupy 23.5%, 51.5% and 25.0%, respectively.
The expected margin income from 1 ha is 85.4
thousand tenge with a volatility of 56.6%. With an
increase in the degree of risk aversion, the
dominance of wheat in the structure of crops
increases. With the coefficient of relative risk
aversion for marginal income equal to 1.2, the
optimal structure of crops is as follows: wheat
occupies 65.8%, peas 9.2%, and flax 25.0%. The
expected margin income per 1 ha is reduced to
77.5 thousand tenge, but the variability is also
reduced to 46.8%.
For the 3rd group of farms, agricultural crops
include wheat, peas and flax, while the share of
each of these crops varies depending on the degree
of risk aversion by the farmer. With the
entrepreneur's indifferent attitude to risk, the share
of wheat is 6.6%, peas 68.4%, flax 25%. The
expected margin income per 1 hectare is 117.3
thousand tenge with a variation of 55.9%. With an
extreme degree of risk aversion (it corresponds to
the coefficient of relative risk aversion for margin
income of 1.2), the share of wheat increases to
65.7%, the share of peas decreases to 9.3%, and
the share of flax remains unchanged. The amount
of expected income from 1 ha of crops is reduced
to 105.1 thousand tenge, the variability also
decreases to 44.0%.
The structure of crops of the 4th group of farms
with an indifferent attitude of the entrepreneur to
the risk includes wheat (75.0%) and flax (25.0%).
At the same time, the expected marginal income
from 1 hectare is 89.2 thousand tenge, the
variability is 46.3%. If the coefficient of relative
risk aversion for margin income is 0.9, peas are
included in the crop structure, and the share of its
crops increases as risk aversion increases. With
extreme reluctance to take risks, wheat (70.2%),
peas (4.8%) and flax (25.0%) are included in the
optimal structure of crops. The amount of expected
income from 1 ha of crops is reduced to 86.3
thousand. tenge, the coefficient of variation is
reduced to 41.4%.
Wheat (75.0%) and rapeseed (25.0%) are
included in the production structure of the 5th
group of farms with an indifferent attitude to risk.
At the same time, the expected margin income per
1 hectare is 96.9 thousand tenge, the variability of
income is 36.2%. The composition of crops and the
structure of crops with a coefficient of relative risk
aversion of 0.3 looks like this: wheat (66.7%),
buckwheat (8.3%), rapeseed (25.0%). The
expected margin income per 1 hectare with such a
degree of risk aversion is 96.7 thousand tenge, the
variability is 33.1%.
On the farms of the 6th group, wheat (75.0%)
and flax (25.0%) predominate in the production
structure. With an extreme degree of risk aversion,
barley appears in the optimal plan: wheat (42.4%),
barley (32.6%), and flax (25.0%). The amount of
expected marginal income per 1 hectare of crops is
decreased from 122.6 thousand tenge to 121.3
thousand tenge, the variability of income is
reduced from 45.7% to 44.5%.
Note that when solving the problem, it was
assumed that there were no restrictions on the
volume of sales of products. The presence of such
conditions, of course, will make changes to
production plans.
In general, there is a certain pattern in changes
in the structure of production, depending on the
degree of farmer’s risk aversion. This pattern is
manifested in the fact that the stronger the risk
aversion, the more diversified the structure of
crops becomes. This feature is consistent with the
findings previously made by many international
and national researchers who studied issues related
to agriculture risk, [16]. It is worth noting that the
long-term predominance of cereals, in particular
wheat, in northern Kazakhstan, inherited from the
former Soviet agriculture, certainly affects the pace
and features of crop diversification in the region.
About 60% of the acreage is still occupied by grain
WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on BUSINESS and ECONOMICS
DOI: 10.37394/23207.2023.20.210
Talgat Kussaiynov, Gulnara Mussina,
Sandugash Tokenova, Saltanat Mambetova
E-ISSN: 2224-2899
2460
Volume 20, 2023
crops. About 70% of the sown area is still occupied
by grain crops, and wheat is the only sown crop on
some farms. In the last decade, the government, by
providing subsidies, began to encourage farmers to
introduce other crops. As a result, oilseed crops
have significantly increased and currently account
for over 20%.
4 Concluding Comments
Farmers in Northern Kazakhstan have limited
flexibility in the choice of activities, which is
caused by relatively unfavorable geographical and
climatic conditions, as well as policy and market
conditions. In these circumstances, it seems that
the size of the farm does not matter much to
influence the choice of a farm plan. The results
indicate that the degree of risk aversion of the
farmer affects the optimal farming plan. Having
only two or three activities, which is normal, can
often capture the majority of risk-reducing benefits
from diversification. The choice of a portfolio is
influenced not only by considerations of
profitability and riskiness of crops, but also by
grain production traditions deeply rooted among
the farmers of the region, and the skills and
knowledge associated with them, as well as the
existing infrastructure. These circumstances
constrain the wider spread of oilseed crops in the
region. And it seems that the size of the farm does
not significantly affect the choice of portfolio. The
potential benefits of farming diversification are an
empirical issue, and it should be addressed on a
case-by-case basis. The question is to choose the
utility function and its parameters that most
accurately reflect the preferences of a particular
farmer.
The study suggests several ideas for further
research. Firstly, no financial management option
was included in the model. Fischer's separation
theorem implies that it is better to diversify
through capital markets than through activity
combinations. In Kazakhstan, the financial markets
of agricultural products are not well developed
either in terms of price or volume. However, a
possible extension of the model would be to
include some types of financial activities, such as
insurance agreements.
Acknowledgments:
The authors express their gratitude to the team of
the research project "Methodology of analysis and
optimization of the socio-economic model (based
on the materials of Northern Kazakhstan)" for the
assistance in collecting data on the socio-economic
development of rural areas. The research has been
funded by a Grant from the Science Committee of
the Ministry of Education and Science of the
Republic of Kazakhstan (Grant No. AP09259525).
References:
[1] Villanueva Ana Bedmar, Michael Halewood,
and I. López Noriega. "Agricultural
biodiversity in climate change adaptation
planning: an analysis of the National
Adaptation Programmes of Action", CCAFS
Working Paper, Vol. 95, 2015.
[2] Chinsinga Blessings, Ronald Mangani, and
Peter Mvula. "The political economy of
adaptation through crop diversification in
Malawi," Ids Bulletin, Vol. 42.3, 2011, pp.
110-117.
[3] Lin Brenda B. "Resilience in agriculture
through crop diversification: adaptive
management for environmental change,
BioScience Vol. 61.3, 2011, pp. 183-193.
[4] Lobell David B., Burke M. B., Tebaldi C.,
Mastrandrea M. D., Falcon W. P., and
Naylor R.. L., "Prioritizing climate change
adaptation needs for food security in 2030",
Science, Vol. 319.5863, 2008, рр.607-610.
[5] Smit Barry, and Mark W. Skinner.
"Adaptation options in agriculture to climate
change: a typology", Mitigation and
adaptation strategies for global change, Vol.
7.1, 2002, рр. 85-114.
[6] Yang Y., Stomph T. J., Makowski D.,
Wopke Van der Werf "Temporal niche
differentiation increases the land equivalent
ratio of annual intercrops: a meta-
analysis" Field Crops Research Vol. 184,
2015, рр. 133-144.
[7] Bell L. W., Moore A. D., and Thomas D. T..
"Diversified crop-livestock farms are risk-
efficient in the face of price and production
variability", Agricultural Systems, Vol. 189,
2021, рр. 103050.
[8] Delgado Christopher L., and Ammar
Siamwalla. "Rural economy and farm
income diversification in developing
countries." Food Security, Diversification
and Resource Management: Refocusing the
Role of Agriculture?. Routledge, 2018, рр.
126-143.
[9] Faye Bernard. "The camel, new challenges
for a sustainable development", Tropical
Animal Health and Production, Vol. 48.4,
2016, рр. 689-692.
WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on BUSINESS and ECONOMICS
DOI: 10.37394/23207.2023.20.210
Talgat Kussaiynov, Gulnara Mussina,
Sandugash Tokenova, Saltanat Mambetova
E-ISSN: 2224-2899
2461
Volume 20, 2023
[10] Dinar A., Hassan R., Mendelsohn R., &
Benhin J. Climate change and agriculture in
Africa: impact assessment and adaptation
strategies, Routledge, 2012.
[11] Schlenker Wolfram, and David B. Lobell.
"Robust negative impacts of climate change
on African agriculture", Environmental
Research Letters, Vol. 5.1, 2010, рр.
014010.
[12] Vigouroux Y., Mariac C., De Mita S., Pham
J. L., Gérard B., Kapran I., & Bezançon G..
"Selection for earlier flowering crop
associated with climatic variations in the
Sahel", PLoS One, Vol. 6.5, 2011, e19563.
[13] Hardaker J. B., Lien G., Anderson J. R., &
Huirne R. B.Coping with risk in agriculture:
Applied decision analysis. Cabi,
Wallingford, 2015.
[14] Anderson Jock R., and John L. Dillon, Risk
analysis in dryland farming systems. No. 2.
Food & Agriculture Org., 1992.
[15] Arrow Kenneth Joseph. "Aspects of the
theory of risk-bearing", Yrjo Jahnssonin
Saatio, Academic Bookstore, Helsinki, 1965.
[16] Kussaiynov T. Modeling and selection of
economic decisions in аagricultural
formations. Nur-Sultan, Saken Seifullin
Kazakh Agrotechnical University, 2020, pp.
102.
WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on BUSINESS and ECONOMICS
DOI: 10.37394/23207.2023.20.210
Talgat Kussaiynov, Gulnara Mussina,
Sandugash Tokenova, Saltanat Mambetova
E-ISSN: 2224-2899
2462
Volume 20, 2023
APPENDIX
Table 1. Marginal income by crops in North-Kazakhstan region, thousand tenge per hectare
Source: Authors ' calculationsнаbased on agricultural statistics Bureau of National Statistics Republic of Kazakhstan
Year
Crops
Wheat
Oats
Buckwheat
Peas
Rapeseed
Flax
Farms with an area of arable land up to 49 ha
2017
34.1
-
-
63.3
-
49.4
2018
19.6
-
-
-22.7
-
63.7
2019
45.9
-
-
38.2
-
82.2
2020
80.8
-
-
38.8
-
114.1
2021
83.1
-
-
49.3
-
147.6
2022
108.2
-
-
99.9
-
143.7
Average
62.0
-
-
33.4
-
91.4
Variability, %
54.8
-
-
85.8
-
38.6
Farms with an area of arable land of 50 to 125 ha
2017
35.9
-
-
126.4
-
57.3
2018
20.7
-
-
-45.2
-
73.6
2019
48.4
-
-
75.9
-
94.9
2020
85.2
-
-
77.4
-
132.1
2021
87.6
-
-
97.7
-
169.9
2022
106.5
-
-
164.3
-
137.1
Average
64.1
-
-
82.8
-
110.8
Variability, %
52.8
-
-
85.8
-
38.6
Farms with an area of arable land of 126 to 344 ha
2017
41.2
32.3
-
141.0
-
102.3
2018
23.7
-14.0
-
-50.4
-
131.4
2019
55.5
21.9
-
84.7
-
169.5
2020
97.6
33.9
-
86.3
-
235.8
2021
95.6
20.9
-
108.9
-
303.5
2022
116.3
16.8
-
183.2
-
244.9
Average
71.6
18.6
-
92.3
-
197.9
Variability, %
51.2
93.1
-
85.8
-
38.6
Farms with an area of arable land of 345 to 799 ha
2017
42.3
55.2
-
59.6
-
67.3
2018
24.4
-24.0
-
-21.3
-
86.5
2019
57.0
37.4
-
35.8
-
111.5
2020
100.4
58.0
-
36.5
-
155.2
2021
103.2
65.5
-
46.0
-
199.8
2022
125.5
52.8
-
77.4
-
161.2
Average
75.5
40.8
-
39.0
-
130.3
Variability, %
52.8
81.0
-
85.8
-
38.6
Farms with an area of arable land of 800 to 1734 ha
2017
42.2
47.9
162.0
97.7
159.8
50.2
2018
24.3
-20.8
92.0
-34.9
146.6
64.5
2019
56.9
32.5
-19.5
58.7
167.8
83.2
2020
100.1
50.4
66.3
59.8
153.2
115.7
2021
102.9
56.9
37.4
75.5
102.8
148.9
2022
125.2
45.9
96.8
126.9
241.2
120.2
Average
75.3
35.5
72.5
63.9
161.9
97.1
Variability, %
52.8
81.0
84.4
85.8
27.8
38.6
Farms with an area of arable land of more than 1735 hectares
2017
54.2
42.9
-
67.5
-
103.7
2018
31.2
-18.6
-
-24.1
-
133.2
2019
73.0
29.1
-
40.5
-
171.7
2020
128.5
45.1
-
41.3
-
239.0
2021
132.1
50.9
-
52.2
-
307.5
2022
160.7
41.0
-
87.7
-
248.2
Average
96.6
31.7
-
44.2
-
200.6
Variability, %
52.8
81.0
-
85.8
-
38.6
WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on BUSINESS and ECONOMICS
DOI: 10.37394/23207.2023.20.210
Talgat Kussaiynov, Gulnara Mussina,
Sandugash Tokenova, Saltanat Mambetova
E-ISSN: 2224-2899
2463
Volume 20, 2023
Table 2. Optimal crop structure depending on the degree of risk aversion
Relative
risk
aversion
ratio
r(z) / r(W)
Sown area by crops, %
Margin income,
thousand
tenge/hectare
Standard deviation,
thousand tenge
Risk ratio, %
Wheat
Barley
Oats
Buckwheat
Peas
Rapeseed
Flax
Farms with an area of arable land up to 49 ha
0/0
0.750
0.000
-
-
0.000
-
0.250
75.5
35.5
47.0
0.5/0.15
0.750
0.000
-
-
0.000
-
0.250
75.5
35.5
47.0
1/0.3
0.669
0.081
-
-
0.000
-
0.250
75.4
35.1
46.6
2/0.6
0.126
0.624
-
-
0.000
-
0.250
75.0
33.4
44.5
3/0.9
0.000
0.750
-
-
0.000
-
0.250
74.9
33.2
44.3
4/1.2
0.000
0.750
-
-
0.000
-
0.250
74.9
33.2
44.3
Farms with an area of arable land of 50 to 125 ha
0/0
0.235
0.000
-
-
0.515
-
0.250
85.4
48.4
56.6
0.5/0.15
0.237
0.000
-
-
0.513
-
0.250
85.3
48.3
56.6
1/0.3
0.288
0.000
-
-
0.462
-
0.250
84.4
46.4
55.0
2/0.6
0.471
0.000
-
-
0.279
-
0.250
81.0
40.5
50.0
3/0.9
0.591
0.000
-
-
0.159
-
0.250
78.7
37.5
47.7
4/1.2
0.658
0.000
-
-
0.092
-
0.250
77.5
36.3
46.8
Farms with an area of arable land of 126 to 344 ha
0/0
0.066
0.000
0.000
-
0.684
-
0.250
117.3
65.6
55.9
0.5/0.15
0.102
0.000
0.000
-
0.648
-
0.250
116.6
64.0
54.9
1/0.3
0.277
0.000
0.000
-
0.473
-
0.250
113.0
56.9
50.3
2/0.6
0.507
0.000
0.000
-
0.243
-
0.250
108.2
49.4
45.7
3/0.9
0.606
0.000
0.000
-
0.144
-
0.250
106.2
47.2
44.4
4/1.2
0.657
0.000
0.000
-
0.093
-
0.250
105.1
46.3
44.0
Farms with an area of arable land of 345 to 799 ha
0/0
0.750
0.000
0.000
-
0.000
-
0.250
89.2
41.3
46.3
0.5/0.15
0.750
0.000
0.000
-
0.000
-
0.250
89.2
41.3
46.3
1/0.3
0.750
0.000
0.000
-
0.000
-
0.250
89.2
41.3
46.3
2/0.6
0.750
0.000
0.000
-
0.000
-
0.250
89.2
41.3
46.3
3/0.9
0.721
0.000
0.000
-
0.029
-
0.250
87.2
40.3
42.4
4/1.2
0.702
0.000
0.000
-
0.048
-
0.250
86.3
38.9
41.4
Farms with an area of arable land of 800 to 1734 ha
0/0
0.750
0,000
0.000
0.000
0
0.25
0
96.9
35.1
36.2
0,5/0,15
0.750
0,000
0.000
0.000
0
0.25
0
96.9
35.1
36.2
1/0,3
0.667
0,000
0.000
0.083
0
0.25
0
96.7
32.0
33.1
2/0,6
0.597
0,000
0.000
0.153
0
0.25
0
96.5
30.2
31.3
3/0,9
0.576
0,000
0.000
0.174
0
0.25
0
96.4
29.9
31.0
4/1,2
0.566
0,000
0.000
0.184
0
0.25
0
96.4
29.8
30.9
Farms with an area of arable land of more than 1735 hectares
0/0
0.750
0.000
0.000
-
0.000
-
0.250
122.6
56.0
45.7
0.5/0.15
0.750
0.000
0.000
-
0.000
-
0.250
122.6
56.0
45.7
1/0.3
0.750
0.000
0.000
-
0.000
-
0.250
122.6
56.0
45.7
2/0.6
0.750
0.000
0.000
-
0.000
-
0.250
122.6
56.0
45.7
3/0.9
0.750
0.000
0.000
-
0.000
-
0.250
122.6
56.0
45.7
4/1.2
0.424
0.326
0.000
-
0.000
-
0.250
121.3
54.0
44.5
WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on BUSINESS and ECONOMICS
DOI: 10.37394/23207.2023.20.210
Talgat Kussaiynov, Gulnara Mussina,
Sandugash Tokenova, Saltanat Mambetova
E-ISSN: 2224-2899
2464
Volume 20, 2023
Contribution of Individual Authors to the
Creation of a Scientific Article (Ghostwriting
Policy)
- Talgat Kussaiynov, Gulnara Mussina carried out
the simulation and the optimization.
- Sandugash Tokenova has organized and
executed the experiments.
- Saltanat Mambetova was responsible for the
Statistics.
Sources of Funding for Research Presented in a
Scientific Article or Scientific Article Itself
The research has been funded by a Grant from the
Science Committee of the Ministry of Education
and Science of the Republic of Kazakhstan (Grant
No. AP09259525).
Conflict of Interest
The authors have no conflict of interest to declare.
Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0
(Attribution 4.0 International, CC BY 4.0)
This article is published under the terms of the
Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0
https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/deed.e
n_US
WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on BUSINESS and ECONOMICS
DOI: 10.37394/23207.2023.20.210
Talgat Kussaiynov, Gulnara Mussina,
Sandugash Tokenova, Saltanat Mambetova
E-ISSN: 2224-2899
2465
Volume 20, 2023